In Conversation: Lauren Falcao Bergquist & Amit Khandelwal on trade & development
The two EGC affiliates discuss how development economics is borrowing from trade models – and vice versa – to better understand global policy challenges.
Development economics and the study of international trade, while traditionally distinct, are increasingly overlapping. Trade economists now pay closer attention to how market frictions like credit constraints or labor market issues affect global trade, and development economists are beginning to utilize tools and models from trade economics to better understand the growth and development process in low- and middle-income countries.
Yale is at the frontier of research on international and domestic trade and the functioning of markets, melding techniques from traditional macroeconomic and microeconomic approaches. Amit Khandelwal, the Dong-Soo Hahn Professor of Global Affairs and Economics, has analyzed the dynamics of the US-China trade war, and Lauren Falcao Bergquist, Assistant Professor of Economics and Global Affairs, runs randomized experiments in African crop markets. Both are EGC affiliates and members of the Markets and Development initiative. In a recent interview, they discussed how insights from their respective subfields are increasingly influencing each other – and the implications for research and policy.
Both of your research focuses on the role of market frictions in trade and development. Why are markets such an important lens?
Bergquist: Development economists think a lot about markets when studying why poor countries are poor or thinking about what’s happening within countries. Markets exist to connect producers and consumers, and when things go wrong, there can be real welfare implications. Agricultural markets, for example, provide income to farmers and food security to consumers – so their proper functioning is critical for livelihoods, consumption, and welfare.
But market frictions and trade costs can create wedges between farmers and consumers. Credit constraints, for instance, can lead to large price fluctuations: if farmers lack access to bank loans, they’re often forced to sell their crops right after harvest, when prices are low, to pay urgent bills – which means that consumers buying food during the lean season will face very high prices, so much so that in many contexts this is called the “hunger season.” Better access to financial markets can lead to less price volatility.
Khandelwal: Markets are a really useful concept in trade, too. When you open up to trade, you can shift resources to sectors with comparative advantage – but in developing countries, that process is often fraught with local market distortions and frictions. If the US imposes new tariffs on China, for example, standard trade models would say that firms in countries like India should expand and export more to the United States. But once an Indian factory exceeds 100 workers, it’s subject to more onerous labor laws. Credit constraints can prevent firms from making investments. Land titling issues can pose major challenges.
In some sense, domestic policy is international policy: while global trade is a powerful force for improving welfare, whether that happens depends on how domestic markets actually function.